Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

A regime changes - Paul Wolfowitz at the World Bank

Collapse
X
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

  • A regime changes - Paul Wolfowitz at the World Bank

    A regime changes - Paul Wolfowitz at the World Bank

    The Economist
    June 4, 2005
    U.S. Edition

    The World Bank's new president is famous for his commitment to "regime
    change". The Bank is committed to a peaceful version of the same thing

    ON ITS way to the Mekong river, the Nam Theun tributary flows
    uninterrupted across the Nakai plateau in Laos, the poorest country in
    South-East Asia. Not for much longer. In March, the World Bank backed a
    proposal to dam it. Hydroelectric turbines will generate up to 1,070 MW
    of electricity, 95% of which will be exported to neighbouring Thailand.

    This is the World Bank's natural habitat, where its compulsions
    and capabilities are both shown to full advantage. The project is
    not just an exercise in hydrology. The Bank's grants will help to
    resettle villagers, including Vietic-speaking hunter-gatherers, from
    the inundated plateau behind the dam and to compensate inhabitants of
    the dried-out riversides below it. As the Bank's International Advisory
    Group reported earlier this year, the displaced are experimenting
    with new ways to make a living, from an organic mulch plant to eel
    breeding. The project will set aside a nature reserve, where wildlife,
    from pangolin to reticulated python, will be defended by village
    gamekeepers, their salaries paid out of the dam's revenues.

    But this is not, it is safe to say, the natural habitat of Paul
    Wolfowitz, who took office as the Bank's new president on June 1st.
    The plight of the reticulated python and the Vietic-speaking peoples
    are unlikely to have crossed his desk in the Pentagon, where he
    previously served as America's deputy secretary of defence. Mr
    Wolfowitz has instead spent most of his career cogitating about
    America's power in the world, representing it abroad and lobbying
    to enlarge it, first in congressional back offices, most recently
    at the intellectual forefront of George Bush's foreign policy. He
    knows little about finance; only a little more about development,
    although, as ambassador to Indonesia for three years, he has lived in
    a populous, poor country. Behind him, he leaves the ongoing nightmare
    of reconstructing Iraq, a project that is certainly behind schedule
    and over budget.

    The Bank which Mr Wolfowitz now heads has as many sides as the Pentagon
    he has left. Speaking on May 31st he said he would be willing to
    listen and experiment, but it will take him some time to get to grips
    with a complex organisation. The Bank's most prominent aspect is the
    International Development Association (IDA), which gives grants ($1.7
    billion last year) and soft loans (another $7.3 billion) to 81 of the
    world's poorest countries. As important, but less widely understood,
    is the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD),
    which lent about $11 billion last year. The IBRD has some claim to
    being a bank rather than a fund. Blessed with a AAA-credit rating,
    it can borrow cheaply on the capital markets, and lend, slightly
    less cheaply, to the aristocracy of the third world, such as China
    and Brazil.

    The Bank also has third and fourth sides-two smaller agencies that
    take on some of the risk of private lending to poor countries-and
    a fifth that settles disputes between foreign lenders and sovereign
    borrowers. Dams in Laos notwithstanding, only 5% of the Bank's money
    went to the energy and mining sectors last year. Three times as much
    went to social services, such as health, while education received 8%.
    The Bank also performs a type of economic chiropractics, giving
    money to governments in need of an "adjustment" in their policies,
    fiscal or monetary.

    Mr Wolfowitz may, in fact, discover much that is familiar to him at
    the Bank. It is first and foremost a formidable technocracy. But
    in its own bloodless idiom, the Bank now talks increasingly about
    politics, even if it does so in euphemisms such as "good governance",
    "capacity building", "voice" and "empowerment". It is committed to
    understanding the political institutions of the countries in which it
    operates. Haltingly, hesitantly, it is also committed to changing them.

    In June 2000, for example, the Bank lent $190m to help finance a
    1,000km pipeline from the oilfields of landlocked Chad to the port of
    Kribi in Cameroon. But laying the pipe was the easy bit. Much harder
    is managing the revenues, which threaten to overvalue Chad's currency
    and underwrite endemic corruption.

    The Bank's answer was two-fold. It insisted that the pipeline revenues
    be paid into an offshore escrow account. About 10% of the money would
    be held aside for future generations. The rest would flow to the
    government's poverty-fighting efforts under the close supervision of a
    new body, commonly known as the Collège. Staffed by parliamentarians,
    judges and representatives from human-rights groups, the Collège was,
    in effect, a new institution of state. It was soon debating whether
    to withhold money from the government. Clearly then, even when it
    is in the business of erecting dams and laying pipelines, the Bank
    is also often building states and reforming regimes.

    That is a big change. Until 1996, politics was the variable that
    dared not speak its name at the Bank. Country directors, who head
    its branch offices in borrowing countries, came to their jobs as
    "self-described political neophytes", according to a recent Bank
    publication that recounts their education in the ways of the world.

    Their initial innocence was largely self-imposed. Basil Kavalsky,
    who served as the Bank's country director across eastern Europe,
    confesses that it was "an article of faith...that we did not take
    political considerations into account." Actually, it was more than
    an article of faith. The Bank's articles of agreement, its founding
    charter, enjoin its officers to remain studiously apolitical.

    Of course, the neophytes soon learned all about the political
    character of their host countries. But, notes Mr Kavalsky, they treated
    corruption as "a given, a part of the environment to be factored into
    the calculation. We did not treat it as a variable-something which
    we should make a concerted effort to address."

    That changed with James Wolfensohn, Mr Wolfowitz's predecessor. It
    was perhaps his most far-reaching innovation in a tumultuous ten-year
    reign. In May 1996, he visited Indonesia, where Mr Wolfowitz had been
    ambassador from 1986 to 1989. The brazen corruption of the country's
    ruling Suharto clan irked them both. Mr Wolfowitz broached the issue,
    albeit politely, as he prepared to leave his ambassadorial post
    in the country in 1989. Seven years later Mr Wolfensohn was more
    forthright. "Let's not mince words," he said at the Bank's 1996
    annual meeting in Washington, DC, "we need to deal with the cancer
    of corruption."

    The following year, the World Development Report, written by a team led
    by Ajay Chhibber, was the first publication in which the Bank properly
    addressed the topic. It was the beginning of a thorough re-examination
    of the role of the state and political institutions in development.

    Mr Chhibber is now given to quoting Napoleon: "institutions alone
    fix the destinies of nations". That dictum finds some support in
    the latest economic research on development. A number of economists
    believe the policies they advocated in the 1980s and 1990s-stabilise
    prices, liberalise trade, privatise industries-matter less than the
    institutions that stand behind those policies.

    Leading the chorus are Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James
    Robinson of the National Bureau of Economic Research. As they point
    out, for example, the prescription of stable finances and sound money
    did little to help in Argentina. The state found itself chronically
    prone to profligacy, for deep institutional reasons. It had to appease
    the country's unruly outlying provinces, which contribute little to
    the economy but dominate parliament. Likewise, they argue, Ghana's
    wildly overvalued exchange rate in its post-independence decades
    was not a monetary blunder. It was a political strategy designed to
    redistribute resources from the country's cocoa exporters, who received
    artificially low prices for their exports, to the import-buying city
    dwellers, on whose support the regime depended.

    Testing such theories is fraught with difficulty. But the measurement
    of institutions has made some progress. Dani Kaufmann, at the World
    Bank, notes an explosion of indicators of good government, most based
    on business surveys or expert perceptions, that offer measures of
    accountability, bureaucratic competence, the rule of law, and so on.
    By sorting and sifting these numbers, he and his colleagues believe
    that they can derive workable measures of misrule. Precise rankings
    between countries are not possible, but broad comparisons are, and
    changes over time can be discerned. Over the past eight years, for
    example, many governments in Africa have defied the Afro-pessimists
    (see table), although more have regressed.

    Mr Kaufmann believes he and his colleagues can demonstrate a strong
    causal link between his indices of sound government and prosperity.
    If the rule of law in Somalia, for example, were to match even that
    prevailing in Laos, Somalia's income would rise two- to three-fold
    in the long run, Mr Kaufmann estimates.

    These are powerful arguments. But even if it is true that institutions
    fix a nation's destiny, can the Bank fix a nation's institutions? Is
    there a reliable "transmission mechanism" between the levers the Bank
    can pull and the results it cares about?

    By training and temperament, Bank staff have tended to view government
    as a practical art. But their efforts to date give comfort to those
    of a more fatalistic cast of mind, who believe good government cannot
    be engineered, but must evolve.

    In 2000, the Bank unveiled its strategy for reforming public
    institutions and strengthening governments. Between 2000 and 2004,
    lending to promote economic reforms fell by 14% a year, but lending
    to improve governance rose by 11%. In the 2004 fiscal year the Bank
    committed 25% of its lending to law and public administration (see
    chart overleaf). It had 220 staff dedicated to the cause, and more
    than 840 professionals affiliated with it.

    For the most part, its direct efforts were confined to poorer
    countries, dependent on IDA for grants and soft loans. The richer
    developing countries, such as Brazil or India, where the state
    apparatus was formidable, were reluctant to cede ground to outsiders.
    In China, where Edwin Lim once served as chief of mission for the Bank,
    "the economic dialogue was always," he admits, "within the Chinese
    ideological and political limits."

    A review of the Bank's efforts to prune the lush bureaucracies of
    African states concluded that civil-service reform remains elusive
    and intractable. Elsewhere, anti-corruption commissions proliferated,
    but achieved little-indeed they were often set up in the wake of some
    scandal as an alternative to doing anything.

    Part of the difficulty, as Dani Rodrik of Harvard University points
    out, is that typical measures capture institutional outcomes, not
    institutional forms. The "rule of law", for example, measures how
    secure an investor feels about his property. It tells us little
    about precisely what makes him feel that way. According to Michael
    Woolcock, of the Bank, and Lant Pritchett, of Harvard University,
    the development industry can agree on "objectives" (children should
    be taught, roads should be passable, the rule of law should prevail)
    and "adjectives" (government should be accountable, transparent and
    responsive). But that is about all. As a result, Mr Kavalsky notes,
    the Bank's prescriptions in this field often come "very close to a
    tautology". What is required for growth? Good governance. And what
    counts as good governance? That which promotes growth.

    But the main difficulty was the obvious one: politics. When the Bank
    moved in on examples of bad governance, it too often forgot to ask,
    bad for whom? Consider, says Mr Chhibber, Turkey's banking system prior
    to that country's financial crisis in 2001. In 1998, the government was
    advised to set up an independent financial regulator, styled on those
    of Britain and Canada. Instead it created a regulator that was packed
    with political appointees. To the Bank's technocrats, it was obvious
    that the country had too many banks, many of them state-owned, and that
    they were not serving the economy at all well. But in Turkey at that
    time, state banks had a different purpose. They were the playthings
    of politicians, given to them as the spoils of electoral victory.

    In such a situation, Mr Chhibber points out, all the Bank can do is
    bide its time. After the 2001 financial crisis, political resistance
    to an independent regulator broke down. Once established, the regulator
    closed more than 20 private banks, and cleaned up the system, at a cost
    of 33% of GNP. Mr Chhibber argues that earlier failures contributed
    to the eventual success. The work undertaken in 1998 allowed Turkey,
    under a new economy minister, Kemal Dervis, himself an alumnus of the
    Bank, to take advantage of the opportunity for reform when it arose.

    In a speech in 2000, Mr Wolfowitz reflected on the thawing of
    authoritarian regimes in South Korea, Taiwan and the Philippines-the
    last of them on his watch as assistant secretary of state for East
    Asia. In these regimes, he noted, America worked on institutional,
    rather than revolutionary, change. It once counted Ferdinand Marcos,
    the dictatorial president of the Philippines, as an ally. If it
    had written him off, it would have lost all influence over him,
    Mr Wolfowitz said. But America could not coddle Marcos indefinitely
    either.

    Such dilemmas will almost certainly revisit Mr Wolfowitz in his
    new job. The Bank must continually choose whether to coddle bad
    governments, or to cut them off. If misrule matters so much for
    development, should it reserve its money for committed reformers,
    turning its back on the reform-shy? That would make its money go
    further; it might also encourage laggards to reform. David Dollar
    and Victoria Levin, two Bank economists, reckon that since 1995
    the Bank's soft-loan arm, IDA, has become much choosier about its
    clients. Broadly speaking, money flows to countries based on two main
    criteria: how well run is it? And how poor?

    IDA may be pickier than it once was, but the Bank as a whole is not
    quite as discriminating as this study suggests. Richer countries,
    even if badly run, can still unlock money from the IBRD, the
    Bank's commercial-loan arm. And disastrously run countries are never
    entirely shunned by IDA. Each gets a small allocation regardless of its
    performance, and some qualify for money from the Bank's £25m trust fund
    for failed states, which it calls "low-income countries under stress".

    Some think that, if it were to confine itself to the well-governed
    parts of the globe, the World Bank would scarcely warrant its title.
    But the Bank is learning that every unfit government is unfit in
    its own way. In some countries, citizens cannot hold policymakers to
    account (China); in others, policymakers cannot bend the bureaucracy
    to their will (Armenia). In some cases, the state is captured by
    venal interests-either wealth captures power (Russia under Yeltsin),
    or power captures wealth (Russia under Putin). In others, the state
    is so weak there is nothing worth capturing.

    The Bank must pitch itself accordingly. If the state is honest, but
    weak, the Bank can try to train judges and equip civil servants. But
    there is no point investing in the machinery of a captured state. A
    project to strengthen the fiscal apparatus of Mobutu Sese Seko, the
    kleptocratic former ruler of Zaire, counts as the most misguided Bank
    project ever, in the opinion of Susan Rose-Ackerman, a corruption
    expert at Yale University.

    If there is no will for reform on the part of government leaders, the
    Bank can try to go over their heads, stimulating demand for reforms
    in the public at large. Sometimes this works. When Thailand slipped
    in the Bank's ratings of good government, Mr Kaufmann recalls, the
    prime minister had to go on the radio to explain himself.

    Some will argue, of course, that foreign aid has been political
    since its inception. The World Bank owes its existence to America's
    strategic commitment to rebuild post-war Europe. And many think the
    modern aid business and the cold war were twin-born at the moment of
    President Harry Truman's inaugural address in 1949. That speech is
    famous for Truman's vow to strengthen the freedom-loving nations of
    the world against the false philosophy of communism. But in it he also
    promised to share America's know-how and some of its resources with
    those parts of the world threatened by the "ancient enemies-hunger,
    misery and despair."

    Mr Wolfowitz, of all people, is not one to disavow Truman's commitment
    to strengthen freedom. But if the ends Truman sought were deeply
    political, the means were mostly technocratic. The Bank which Mr
    Wolfowitz now leads is in a different game. The ends it pursues
    are primarily technocratic-it wants to fight poverty, not a false
    philosophy. But the means it employs have to be canny, opportunistic
    and, yes, political.

    --Boundary_(ID_BJhvHDovArXcEoXbPZbvlg)--
Working...
X